A Monetary History of the United States

A Monetary History of the United States, 1867–1960
Dust jacket of 1st Edition, 3rd printing
AuthorMilton Friedman, Anna Schwartz
CountryUnited States
LanguageEnglish
SubjectEconomic history
GenreHistory
Published1963
Princeton University Press
Media typePrint (hardcover)
Pages860 pp (first edition)
OCLC258805
Dewey Decimal
332.4973
LC ClassHG538.F86 1963

A Monetary History of the United States, 1867–1960 is a book written in 1963 by Nobel Prize–winning economist Milton Friedman and Anna J. Schwartz. It uses historical time series and economic analysis to argue the then-novel proposition that changes in the money supply profoundly influenced the U.S. economy, especially the behavior of economic fluctuations. The implication they draw is that changes in the money supply had unintended adverse effects, and that sound monetary policy is necessary for economic stability. Orthodox economic historians see it as one of the most influential economics books of the century.[1][2] The chapter dealing with the causes of the Great Depression was published as a stand-alone book titled The Great Contraction, 1929–1933.[3]

Authorship

Milton Friedman and Anna Schwartz were working at the National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) when the future chairman of the Federal Reserve, Arthur Burns, suggested that they collaborate on a project to analyze the effect of the money supply on the business cycle.[4] Schwartz was already gathering much of the relevant historical data at that point, while Friedman was already a professor at the University of Chicago and also at the NBER. They began work in the late 1940s and eventually published A Monetary History through Princeton University Press in 1963. The Depression-related chapter, "The Great Contraction," was republished as a separate book in 1965.[5][6]

Content

The book discusses the role of the monetary policy in the U.S. economy from the Civil War Reconstruction Era to the middle of the 20th century. It presents what was then a contrarian view of the role of monetary policy in the Great Depression. The prevalent view in the early 1960s was that monetary forces played a passive role in the economic contraction of the 1930s. The Monetary History argues that the bank failures and the massive withdrawals of currency from the financial system that followed significantly shrank the money supply (the total amount of currency and outstanding bank deposits), which greatly exacerbated the economic contraction. The book criticizes the Federal Reserve for not keeping the supply of money steady and not acting as lender of last resort, instead allowing commercial banks to fail and allowing the economic depression to deepen.[7]

Themes

The book's main theme is the money supply. It tracks this through three numbers:

  • the ratio of cash that people hold in their checking deposits (when people trust banks, they deposit more of their money)
  • the ratio of bank deposits to bank reserves (when banks feel safer, they loan out more of their money)
  • high-powered money (that is, anything that serves as cash or reserves)

The money supply (cash + deposits) can be computed from these three numbers. The supply shrinks when people withdraw money from the bank, banks hold more reserves, or high-powered money leaves the country (e.g., gold is exported). During a crisis, all three can happen.

Another theme is gold. For the time period, it was the unit used for international trade with Europe. So even when the US is not on the gold standard, it plays a significant role. The authors are precise about the gold standard. The authors say the US was on the gold standard from 1879 to 1923. That is, paper money could be exchanged for bullion and international trade was settled immediately with gold. From 1923 to 1933, the authors say that international trade was "sterilized" by the Fed inflating the money rather than immediately being settled by gold. Lastly, they term the period from 1934 to 1960 (when the book was published) as a "managed standard". Paper money cannot be exchanged for bullion. The authors compare gold to a subsidized commodity, like grain.

Another theme is silver. China and Mexico used it for their currency and the US used it for smaller coins. From 1879 to 1897, there was a populist push to switch the gold-backed dollar to silver. The US Treasury bought silver, but that didn't help when the country was on gold. Later, during the Great Depression, the US bought gold at inflated prices to help silver miners. The result was tragic for the money supplies of China and Mexico.

The authors measure the velocity of money. The authors talk about it a lot, but do not make any conclusions about it.

Lastly, a theme is decision making at the Federal Reserve. The authors try to find out the people making the decisions and what information they had. Probably just as important is the decision-making process. The NY Fed Bank initially lead the decision-making process, but eventually it migrated to the Federal Reserve Board in Washington, DC. To a lesser extent, the Secretary of the Treasury's decisions are included.

Thesis

The thesis of Monetary History is that the money supply affects the economy. In the final chapter, they specify 3 occasions where the Federal Reserve acted strongly during relatively calm times and present these as an experiment for the reader to judge their thesis.

The three actions by the Fed were the raising the discount rate in 1920, the raise of it in 1931, and the raise of the reserve requirement in 1937. Each of these actions caused a large contraction of the money supply over the next 12 months (9%, 14%, 3%). In fact, these were the three sharpest declines they saw in their data. In those 12 months, industrial production fell dramatically (30%, 24%, 34%). Other metrics fell at similar rates. These were 3 of the 6 worst 12-month periods for industrial production. The others were 1929-1931 (the Great Depression) and 1945, when the economy switched from wartime to peacetime production.

Having demonstrated their thesis, they can now use it. They claim that the Great Depression was due to the Fed letting the money supply shrink from 1929 to 1933.

Great Depression

Friedman and Schwartz identified four main policy mistakes made by the Federal Reserve that led to a sharp and undesirable decline in the money supply:[7]

  • In the spring of 1928, the Federal Reserve began to tighten its monetary policy (resulting in rising interest rates) and continued that same policy until the stock market crash of October 1929. This tight monetary policy caused the economy to enter a recession in mid-1929 and triggered the stock market crash a few months later.
  • In the fall of 1931, it raised interest rates to defend the dollar in response to speculative attacks, ignoring the difficulties this caused to domestic commercial banks.
  • After lowering interest rates early in 1932 with positive results, it raised interest rates again in late 1932, causing a further collapse in the U.S. economy.
  • The Federal Reserve was also to be blamed for a pattern of ongoing neglect of problems in the U.S. banking sector throughout the early 1930s. It failed to create a stable domestic banking environment by supporting the domestic banks and acting as lender of last resort to domestic banks during banking panics.

Influence

The book was the first to present the then novel argument that excessively tight monetary policy by the Federal Reserve following the boom of the 1920s turned an otherwise normal recession into the Great Depression of the 1930s. Previously, the consensus of economists was that loss of investor and consumer confidence following the Wall Street Crash of 1929 was a primary cause of the Great Depression.[citation needed]

The Monetary History was lauded as one of the most influential economics books of the twentieth century by the Cato Institute book forum in 2003.[8] It was also cited with approval in a 2002 speech by then-Federal Reserve board member Ben Bernanke stating "the direct and indirect influences of the Monetary History on contemporary monetary economics would be difficult to overstate",[9][10] and again in a 2004 speech as "transform[ing] the debate about the Great Depression".[7]

The Depression-related chapter of A Monetary History was titled "The Great Contraction" and was republished as a separate book in 1965. Some editions include an appendix[11] in which the authors got an endorsement from an unlikely source at an event in their honor when Ben Bernanke made this statement:

Let me end my talk by abusing slightly my status as an official representative of the Federal Reserve. I would like to say to Milton and Anna: Regarding the Great Depression, you're right. We did it. We're very sorry. But thanks to you, we won't do it again.[12][13]

Monetarist economists used the work of Friedman and Schwartz to justify their positions for using monetary policy as the critical economic stabilizer. This view became more popular as Keynesian stabilizers failed to ameliorate the stagflation of the 1970s and political winds shifted away from government intervention in the market into the 1980s and 1990s.

Criticism

The book lays most of the blame for the Great Depression upon the Federal Reserve, arguing that it did not do enough to prevent the Depression. Economists such as Peter Temin have raised questions about whether or not most monetary quantity levels were endogenous rather than exogenously determined, as A Monetary History argues, especially during the Depression.[14] Paul Krugman has argued that the 2008 financial crisis has shown that, during a financial crisis, central banks cannot control broad money, and that money supply bears little relationship to GDP. According to Krugman, the same was true in the 1930s, and the claim that the Federal Reserve could have prevented the Great Depression is highly dubious.[15][16]

Economic historian Barry Eichengreen, in The Golden Fetters, has argued that because of the then internationally prevailing gold exchange standard, the Federal Reserve's hands were tied. According to Eichengreen, in order to maintain the credibility of the gold standard, the Federal Reserve could not undertake actions (such as drastically increasing the money supply) in the manner advocated by Friedman and Schwartz.[17]

James Tobin, while appreciating the rigor with which Friedman and Schwartz demonstrated the importance of the monetary supply, questions their measures of the velocity of money and how informative this measure of the frequency of monetary transactions really is in order to understand the macroeconomic fluctuations of the early-to-mid 20th century.[18]

Austrian Anarcho-Capitalist economist Murray Rothbard has argued that the money supply actually increased during the time period where Friedman claimed the Federal Reserve contracted the money supply. He uses this argument to say that the Great Depression was a manifestation of the Austrian Business Cycle Theory. Although Rothbard and Friedman both hold the belief that the Great Depression was a result of the Federal Reserve.[19]

See also

Notes

  1. ^ Michael D. Bordo; Hugh Rockoff (2013). "Not Just the Great Contraction: Friedman and Schwartz's A Monetary History of the United States 1867 to 1960". American Economic Review. 103 (3): 61–65. doi:10.1257/aer.103.3.61. JSTOR 23469704. S2CID 154748046.
  2. ^ O'Sullivan, Mary A. (2021). "History as heresy: Unlearning the lessons of economic orthodoxy". The Economic History Review. 75 (2): 297–335. doi:10.1111/ehr.13117. ISSN 1468-0289. S2CID 244299719.
  3. ^ Milton Friedman; Anna Jacobson Schwartz (2008). The Great Contraction, 1929–1933 (New ed.). Princeton University Press. ISBN 978-0691137940.
  4. ^ Friedman, Milton (1989). "Collaboration in Economics". In Bordo, Michael D. (ed.). Money, History, and International Finance: Essays in Honor of Anna J. Schwartz. Chicago and London: The University of Chicago Press. pp. 248. ISBN 9780226065939.
  5. ^ Milton Friedman; Anna Jacobson Schwartz; National Bureau of Economic Research (2008). "B. Bernanke's speech to M. Friedman". The Great Contraction, 1929–1933. Princeton University Press. p. 247. ISBN 978-0-691-13794-0.
  6. ^ Feldstein, Martin (April 14, 2000), "Remarks made by Martin Feldstein April 14, 2000 at a dinner honoring Anna Schwartz's 85th birthday", Anna Schwartz at the National Bureau of Economic Research. Retrieved March 15, 2011
  7. ^ a b c Bernanke, Ben (March 2, 2004). "Money, Gold, and the Great Depression". Remarks by Governor Ben S. Bernanke at the H. Parker Willis Lecture in Economic Policy. Federal Reserve Board website. Archived from the original on August 30, 2009. Retrieved August 19, 2009.
  8. ^ "A Monetary History of the United States, 1867–1960". Archived Events, Book Forum. Cato Institute website. Retrieved August 6, 2013.
  9. ^ Bernanke, Ben (November 8, 2002). "On Milton Friedman's Ninetieth Birthday". Remarks by Governor Ben S. Bernanke at the Conference to Honor Milton Friedman, University of Chicago, Chicago, Illinois. Federal Reserve Board website. Retrieved January 17, 2013.
  10. ^ Milton Friedman; Anna Jacobson Schwartz; National Bureau of Economic Research (2008). "B. Bernanke's speech to M. Friedman". The Great Contraction, 1929-1933. Princeton University Press. p. 247. ISBN 978-0-691-13794-0.
  11. ^ Milton Friedman; Anna Jacobson Schwartz; National Bureau of Economic Research (2008). "B. Bernanke's speech to M. Friedman". The Great Contraction, 1929–1933. Princeton University Press. p. 247. ISBN 978-0-691-13794-0.
  12. ^ Ben Bernanke (November 8, 2002), FederalReserve.gov: Conference to Honor Milton Friedman, University of Chicago
  13. ^ Milton Friedman; Anna Jacobson Schwartz; National Bureau of Economic Research (2008). "B. Bernanke's speech to M. Friedman". The Great Contraction, 1929–1933. Princeton University Press. p. 247. ISBN 978-0-691-13794-0.
  14. ^ Temin, Peter. "Review: Money, Money Everywhere: A Retrospective Review. Reviewed work(s): A Monetary History of the United States, 1867-1960. By Milton Friedman; Anna Jacobson Schwartz." Reviews in American History, Vol. 5, No. 2 (Jun., 1977), pp. 151-159 (via jstor.org)
  15. ^ Krugman, Paul (May 1, 2012). "Milton's Paradise Lost". New York Times. Retrieved June 27, 2014.
  16. ^ Krugman, Paul (August 8, 2013). "Milton Friedman, Unperson". New York Times. Retrieved June 27, 2014.
  17. ^ Eichengreen, Barry J. (1992). Golden Fetters: the Gold Standard and the Great Depression, 1919–1939. New York: Oxford University Press. ISBN 978-0-19-506431-5.
  18. ^ Tobin, James (1965). "The Monetary Interpretation of History". American Economic Review. 55 (3): 464–485. JSTOR 1814559.
  19. ^ Rothbard, 1962, America's Great Depression

External links

A Monetary History of the United States, 1867-1960 at Google Books