Industrial policy

Official strategic effort to encourage the development and growth of all or part of the economy
Public finance
Detail from the mural "Government" by Elihu Vedder in the Library of Congress
Policies
  • Agricultural
  • Economic
  • Energy
  • Industrial
  • Investment
  • Social
  • Trade
  • Fiscal
  • Monetary
  • Policy mix
Fiscal policy
  • Budget
    • policy
  • Debt
    • internal
  • Deficit / surplus
  • Finance ministry
  • Fiscal union
  • Revenue
  • Spending
  • Tax
  • Portal
  • v
  • t
  • e

Industrial policy is government policy to encourage the development and growth of all or part of the economy in pursuit of some public goal.[1][2][3][4] Historically, it has often focused on the manufacturing sector, militarily important sectors, or on fostering an advantage in new technologies. The government takes measures "aimed at improving the competitiveness and capabilities of domestic firms and promoting structural transformation".[5] A country's infrastructure (including transportation, telecommunications and energy industry) is a major enabler of industrial policy.[6]

Industrial policies are interventionist measures typical of mixed economy countries. Many types of industrial policies contain common elements with other types of interventionist practices such as trade policy. Industrial policy is usually seen as separate from broader macroeconomic policies, such as tightening credit and taxing capital gains. Traditional examples of industrial policy include subsidizing export industries and import-substitution-industrialization (ISI), where trade barriers are temporarily imposed on some key sectors, such as manufacturing.[7] By selectively protecting certain industries, these industries are given time to learn (learning by doing) and upgrade. Once competitive enough, these restrictions are lifted to expose the selected industries to the international market.[8] More contemporary industrial policies include measures such as support for linkages between firms and support for upstream technologies.[9]

Economists have debated the role of industrial policy in fostering industrialization and economic development.[1]

History

The traditional arguments for industrial policies go back as far as the 18th century. Prominent early arguments in favor of selective protection of industries were contained in the 1791 Report on the Subject of Manufactures[10] of US economist and politician Alexander Hamilton, as well as the work of German economist Friedrich List.[11] List's views on free trade were in explicit contradiction to those of Adam Smith,[12] who, in The Wealth of Nations, said that "the most advantageous method in which a landed nation can raise up artificers, manufacturers, and merchants of its own is to grant the most perfect freedom of trade to the artificers, manufacturers, and merchants of all other nations."[13]

According to NYU historians Prince & Taylor, "The relationship between government and industry in the United States has never been a simple one, and the labels used in categorizing these relationships at different times are often misleading if not false. In the early nineteenth century, for example, it is quite clear that the laissez faire label is an inappropriate one."[14][neutrality is disputed] In the US, an industrial policy was explicitly presented for the first time by the Jimmy Carter administration in August 1980, but it was subsequently dismantled with the election of Ronald Reagan the following year.[15]

Historically, there is a growing consensus that most developed countries, including United Kingdom, United States, Germany, and France, have intervened actively in their domestic economy through industrial policies.[16] These early examples are followed by interventionist ISI strategies pursued in Latin American countries such as Brazil, Mexico or Argentina.[8] More recently, the rapid growth of East Asian economies, or the newly industrialized countries (NICs), has also been associated with active industrial policies that selectively promoted manufacturing and facilitated technology transfer and industrial upgrading.[17] The success of these state-directed industrialization strategies are often attributed to developmental states and strong bureaucracies such as the Japanese MITI.[18] According to Princeton's Atul Kohli, the reason Japanese colonies such as South Korea developed so rapidly and successfully was down to Japan exporting to its colonies the same centralised state development that it had used to develop itself.[19] Precisely speaking, South Korea's development can be explained by the fact that it followed the similar industrial policies that UK, US and Germany implemented, and South Korea adopted Export-Oriented Industrialization (EOI) policy from 1964 based on its own decision contrary to the Import Substitution Industrialization (ISI) policy touted by international aid organizations and experts at that time.[20] Many of these domestic policy choices, however, are now seen as detrimental to free trade and are hence limited by various international agreements such as WTO TRIMs or TRIPS. Instead, the recent focus for industrial policy has shifted towards the promotion of local business clusters and the integration into global value chains.[21]

During the Reagan administration, an economic development initiative called Project Socrates was initiated to address US decline in ability to compete in world markets. Project Socrates, directed by Michael Sekora, resulted in a computer-based competitive strategy system that was made available to private industry and all other public and private institutions that impact economic growth, competitiveness and trade policy. A key objective of Socrates was to utilize advanced technology to enable US private institutions and public agencies to cooperate in the development and execution of competitive strategies without violating existing laws or compromising the spirit of "free market". President Reagan was satisfied that this objective was fulfilled in the Socrates system. Through the advances of innovation age technology, Socrates would provide "voluntary" but "systematic" coordination of resources across multiple "economic system" institutions including industry clusters, financial service organizations, university research facilities and government economic planning agencies. While the view of one US President and the Socrates team was that technology made it virtually possible for both to exist simultaneously, the industrial policy vs. free market debate continued as later under the George H. W. Bush administration, Socrates was labeled as industrial policy and de-funded.[22][23]

Following the Financial Crisis of 2007–08, many countries around the world – including the US, UK, Australia, Japan and most countries of the European Union – have adopted industry policies. However contemporary industry policy generally accepts globalization as a given, and focuses less on the decline of older industries, and more on the growth of emergent industries. It often involves the government working collaboratively with industry to respond to challenges and opportunities.[24] China is a prominent case where the central and subnational governments participate in nearly all economic sectors and processes. Even though market mechanisms have gained importance, state guidance through state-directed investment and indicative planning plays a substantial role in the economy. In order to catch-up and even overtake industrialized countries technologically, China's "state activities even extend to efforts to prevent the dominance of foreign investors and technologies in areas considered to be of key significance such as the strategic industries and the new technologies"[25] including robotics and new energy vehicles.

Criticism

Some criticize industrial policy based on the concept of government failure. Industrial policy is seen as harmful as governments lack the required information, capabilities, and incentives to successfully determine whether the benefits of promoting certain sectors above others exceeds the costs and in turn implement the policies.[26] While the East Asian Tigers provided successful examples of heterodox interventions and protectionist industrial policies,[27] industrial policies such as import-substitution-industrialization (ISI) have failed in many other regions such as Latin America and Sub-Saharan Africa. Governments, in making decisions with regard to electoral or personal incentives, can be captured by vested interests, leading to industrial policies supporting local rent-seeking political elites while distorting the efficient allocation of resources by market forces.[28]

Debates on process

Despite criticism, there is a consensus in recent development theory that says state interventions may be necessary when market failures occur.[29] Market failures often exist in the form of externalities and natural monopolies. Some economists argue that public action can boost certain development factors "beyond what market forces on their own would generate."[30] In practice, these interventions are often aimed at regulating networks, public infrastructure, R&D or correcting information asymmetries. Many countries are now seeing a revival of industrial policy.[31]

One question is which kinds of industrial policy are most effective in promoting economic development. For example, economists debate whether developing countries should focus on their comparative advantage by promoting mostly resource- and labor-intensive products and services, or invest in higher-productivity industries, which may only become competitive in the longer term.[32]

Debate also surrounds the issue of whether government failures are more pervasive and severe than market failures.[33] Some argue that the lower the government accountability and capabilities, the higher the risk of political capture of industrial policies, which may be economically more harmful than existing market failures.[34]

Of particular relevance for developing countries are the conditions under which industrial policies may also contribute to poverty reduction, such as a focus on specific industries or the promotion of linkages between larger companies and smaller local enterprises.[35]

See also

References

  1. ^ a b Juhász, Réka; Steinwender, Claudia (2024). "Industrial Policy and the Great Divergence". Annual Review of Economics. doi:10.1146/annurev-economics-091523-044259. hdl:10419/282363. ISSN 1941-1383.
  2. ^ Graham 1994, p. 3.
  3. ^ Bingham 1998, p. 21.
  4. ^ Rodrik 2004, p. 2. Rodrik uses the term in a more extended fashion, such as to encompass "non-traditional activities in agriculture or services. There is no evidence that the types of market failures that call for industrial policy are located predominantly in industry".
  5. ^ UNCTAD & UNIDO 2011, p. 34.
  6. ^ For the relations between industrial policy and infrastructure, see Koh, Jae Myong (2018) Green Infrastructure Financing: Institutional Investors, PPPs and Bankable Projects, Palgrave Macmillan, pp. 12–51.
  7. ^ Krugman 1987.
  8. ^ a b Gereffi & Wyman 1990.
  9. ^ Wear, Andrew (2017-01-24). "Industry policy emerges from globalisation resurgent and more important than ever". The Mandarin. Retrieved 26 January 2017.
  10. ^ Hamilton 1827.
  11. ^ List 1909.
  12. ^ List 1909, Book III, [1].
  13. ^ Smith 1776, Book IV, Chapter 9 [2].
  14. ^ Prince & Taylor 1982, p. 283.
  15. ^ Graham 1994, p. 27.
  16. ^ Chang 2002.
  17. ^ Wade 2003.
  18. ^ Johnson 1982.
  19. ^ Kohli 2004.
  20. ^ Koh 2018, pp. 28–39.
  21. ^ Humphrey & Schmitz 2000.
  22. ^ Smith, Esther (5 May 1988). "DoD Unveils Competitive Tool: Project Socrates Offers Valuable Analysis". Washington Technology.
  23. ^ Markoff, John (10 May 1990). "Technology Official Quits At Pentagon". The New York Times. Retrieved 25 August 2012.
  24. ^ Wear, Andrew (2017-01-24). "Industry policy emerges from globalization resurgent and more important than ever". The Mandarin. Retrieved 26 January 2017.
  25. ^ Heilmann, Sebastian (2017). China's Political System. Rowman & Littlefield. p. 240. Archived from the original on 2017-04-26. Retrieved 2017-04-26.
  26. ^ See for instance, regarding the medias industries: Violaine Hacker, « Citoyenneté culturelle et politique européenne des médias : entre compétitivité et promotion des valeurs », Nations, Cultures et Entreprises en Europe, sous la direction de Gilles Rouet, Collection Local et Global, L’Harmattan, Paris, pp. 163–84
  27. ^ Amsden 1992.
  28. ^ Pack & Saggi 2006.
  29. ^ Rodrik 2009.
  30. ^ Rodrik 2004, p. 1. "Perhaps not surprisingly, this recognition is now particularly evident in those parts of the world where market-oriented reforms were taken the farthest and the disappointment about the outcomes is correspondingly the greatest – notably in Latin America".
  31. ^ "Many countries are seeing a revival of industrial policy". The Economist.
  32. ^ Lin & Chang 2009.
  33. ^ Khan 2003.
  34. ^ Kaufmann & Krause 2009.
  35. ^ Altenburg 2011.

Sources

Library resources about
Industrial policy
  • Resources in your library
  • Resources in other libraries
  • Altenburg, Tilman (2011). Industrial Policy in Developing Countries: Overview and lessons from seven country cases (PDF). Bonn: German Development Institute. ISBN 978-3-889-85533-6. Retrieved 25 August 2012.
  • Amsden, Alice H. (1992). Asia's Next Giant: South Korea and Late Industrialization. Oxford: Oxford University Press. ISBN 978-0-195-07603-5.
  • Bingham, Richard D. (1998). Industrial Policy American Style: From Hamilton to HDTV. Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe. ISBN 978-1-563-24596-1.
  • Carey, Mathew (1826). Cursory View of the Liberal and Restrictive Systems of Political Economy. Philadelphia, PA: J. R. A. Skerrett.
  • Chang, Ha-Joon (2002). Kicking Away the Ladder: Development Strategy in Historical Perspective: Policies and Institutions for Economic Development in Historical Perspective. London: Anthem Press. ISBN 978-1-843-31027-3.
  • Cimoli, Mario; Dosi, Giovanni; Stiglitz, Joseph E., eds. (2009). Industrial Policy and Development: The Political Economy of Capabilities Accumulation. Oxford: Oxford University Press. ISBN 978-0-199-23526-1.
  • Dobbin, Frank. Forging Industrial Policy: The United States, Britain and France in the Railway Age. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press 1994
  • Gereffi, Gary; Wyman, Donald L. (1990). Manufacturing Miracles: Paths of Industrialization in Latin America and East Asia. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. ISBN 978-0-691-02297-0.
  • Graham, Otis L. (1994). Losing Time: The Industrial Policy Debate. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. ISBN 978-0-674-53935-8.
  • Hamilton, Alexander (1827) [1791]. "Report on the Subject of Manufactures". Philadelphia, PA: William Brown. Retrieved 25 August 2012. {{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  • Heilmann, Sebastian, ed. (2017). China's Political System. Rowman & Littlefield. ISBN 978-1-4422-7736-6. Archived from the original on 2017-04-26. Retrieved 2017-04-26.
  • Humphrey, John; Schmitz, Hubert (2000). Governance and Upgrading: Linking Industrial Cluster and Global Value Chain Research. Institute of Development Studies. ISBN 1-8586-4334-1.
  • Johnson, Chalmers (1982). MITI and the Japanese Miracle: The Growth of Industrial Policy, 1925–1975. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press. ISBN 0-8047-1128-3.
  • Kaufmann, Friedrich; Krause, Matthias (2009). "Industrial Policy in Mozambique" (PDF). German Development Institute. Archived from the original (PDF) on 18 October 2012. Retrieved 25 August 2012. {{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  • Khan, Mushtaq H. (2003). "State Failure in Developing Countries and Strategies of Institutional Reform" (PDF). In B. Tungodden; N. Stern; I. Kolstad (eds.). Toward Pro-Poor Policies: Aid, Institutions, and Globalization. Oxford University Press and World Bank. pp. 165–195. Retrieved 25 August 2012.
  • Koh, Jae Myong (2018). Green Infrastructure Financing: Institutional Investors, PPPs and Bankable Projects, London: Palgrave Macmillan. ISBN 978-3-319-71769-2.
  • Kohli, Atul (2004). State-Directed Development: Political Power and Industrialization in the Global Periphery. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. ISBN 978-0-521-54525-9.
  • Krugman, Paul (1987). "The narrow moving band, the Dutch disease, and the competitive consequences of Mrs. Thatcher" (PDF). Journal of Development Economics. 27 (1–2): 41–55. doi:10.1016/0304-3878(87)90005-8. Archived from the original (PDF) on 2012-09-11. Retrieved 2012-08-24.
  • Lin, Justin; Chang, Ha-Joon (2009). "Should Industrial Policy in Developing Countries Conform to Comparative Advantage or Defy it? A Debate Between Justin Lin and Ha-Joon Chang" (PDF). Development Policy Review. 27 (5): 483–502. doi:10.1111/j.1467-7679.2009.00456.x. S2CID 17063817. Retrieved 25 August 2012.
  • List, Friedrich (1909) [1841]. The National System of Political Economy. London: Longmans, Green, and Co.
  • McKenzie, Richard B. (2002). "Industrial Policy". In David R. Henderson (ed.). Concise Encyclopedia of Economics (1st ed.). Library of Economics and Liberty. OCLC 317650570, 50016270, 163149563
  • Okuno-Fujiwara, Masahiro (1991). "Industrial Policy in Japan: A Political Economy View" (PDF). In Paul Krugman (ed.). Trade with Japan: Has the Door Opened Wider?. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press. pp. 271–304. ISBN 0-226-45458-4. Retrieved 25 August 2012.
  • Pack, Howard; Saggi, Kamal (2006). The case for industrial policy: a critical survey (PDF). World Bank. Retrieved 25 August 2012.
  • Prince, Carl E.; Taylor, Seth (1982). "Daniel Webster, the Boston Associates, and the U.S. Government's Role in the Industrializing Process, 1815–1830". Journal of the Early Republic. 2 (3): 283–299. doi:10.2307/3122975. JSTOR 3122975.
  • Rodrik, Dani (2004). "Industrial Policy for the Twenty-First Century". Industrial Policy for the 21st Century. UNIDO. Archived from the original on 12 May 2013. Retrieved 24 August 2012.
  • Rodrik, Dani (2009). "Industrial Policy: Don't Ask Why, Ask How". Middle East Development Journal. 1 (1): 1–29. doi:10.1142/S1793812009000024. S2CID 155012777.
  • Smith, Adam (1776). An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. London: W Strahan and T Cadell.
  • UNCTAD; UNIDO (2011). "Economic Development in Africa Report 2011: Fostering Industrial Development in Africa in the New Global Environment" (PDF). United Nations. Retrieved 27 August 2012. {{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  • Wade, Robert (2003). Governing the Market: Economic Theory and the Role of Government in East Asian Industrialization. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. ISBN 978-0-691-11729-4.

External links

  • New Industrial and Innovation Policy, The World Bank Institute
  • China's Political System, Mercator Institute for China Studies
  • Interview with US secretary of commerce Penny Pritzke by the McKinsey Global Institute
  • v
  • t
  • e
Fields
Other topics
Authority control databases Edit this at Wikidata
National
  • Spain
  • Germany
  • Israel
  • United States
  • Japan
  • Czech Republic
Other
  • NARA